The Failure of the Liberal Economic Experiment?
By James K. Glassman CommentaryMagazine.comThe
plunge in the U.S. economy in 2008 and 2009 became an irresistible opportunity
to pronounce the failure of the form of capitalism that emerged at the end of
the 20th century. “One had expected competition and abundance for everyone, but
instead one got scarcity, the triumph of profit-oriented thinking, speculation
and dumping,” said Nicolas Sarkozy, the president of France. The current crisis,
he noted with a certain pleasure, signaled the end of the “illusion of public
impotence” and the “return of the state.”
There was ample reason for such grave-dancing. Between July 1, 2008, and June
30, 2009, total U.S. economic output, adjusted for inflation, dropped at an
annual rate of 3.8 percent—the worst 12-month decline since 1946. The
unemployment rate, which started 2008 at 5 percent, had doubled by the fall of
2010. The number of jobs fell for 21 months in a row, and by May 2010 the median
unemployed worker had been out of work for 23 weeks—compared with 10 weeks in
the depths of the 1973-75 recession.
The quarter-century that began shortly after Ronald Reagan’s election had
been widely viewed as a period in which a free-market approach had proved its
superiority to state direction of economies. In the -United States, cutting top
income tax rates in half, reducing regulatory burdens, and spreading free trade
seemed to have produced significant prosperity and remarkable stability. Between
1983 and 2008, gross domestic product grew at an average of 3.2 percent
annually. Only once did output fall in a calendar year, and that was by just
two-tenths of a percentage point. Inflation, interest rates, and unemployment
were tame.1
Then, suddenly, an asset bubble in real estate exploded, the growth and
stability vanished, and the United States suffered its worst economic misery in
(take your pick) 34, 53, or 71 years. So you would expect that the American
public, following President Sarkozy, would see the recession as a severe
setback—or even a death blow—to conservative economic policies that were aimed
at limiting the power of government and liberating the private sector.
You would have expected that, and you would have been right—but only briefly.
Since the beginning of 2010, a surprising reversal has occurred. Rather than
supporting and encouraging government intervention to mitigate an economic
calamity caused by “profit-oriented thinking,” Americans have come to believe
that government has failed to fix the problem and may, in fact, have made it
worse. Now it is liberal, not conservative, economic policies that are
suddenly in jeopardy.
_____________
While the recession has at least bottomed out and appears technically to
have ended, the recovery, by historic standards, has been anemic. Within two
years of the start of every one of the three previous recessions, GDP had
rebounded significantly—to 4 percentage points above where it was when the
downturn began. But 31 months after the start of the current recession, GDP was
still below its starting point. The employment situation is even worse. In the
nasty recession of 1981-82, the economy had regained the jobs it lost within
just 26 months. This time around, we still have 5 percent fewer jobs than at the
recession’s start in December 2007.
What bothers the public, plain and simple, is that the steps that were taken
to mitigate the recession—which involved greater government involvement,
including ownership of the largest auto and insurance companies, and vastly more
federal spending—have not worked.
Worse, the public believes federal action was especially unhelpful to the
mass of Americans. Only 27 percent of respondents to a Pew Research Center/-National
Journal survey in July agreed that “government economic policies have
helped [the] middle class.” A poll in June by Greenberg Quinlan Rosner Research
for Democracy Corps, a Democratic organization, asked American adults to choose
between two statements:
1: President Obama’s economic policies helped avert an even worse crisis and
are laying the foundation for our eventual recovery.
or
2 : President Obama’s economic policies have run up a record federal deficit
while failing to end the recession or slow job losses.
By 49 percent to 44 percent, respondents chose Statement No. 2, and for those
who identified themselves as independents, the margin was 52-38. Among
independents, the results for backing a statement “strongly” were 42 percent for
No. 2 and just 22 percent for No. 1.
Some politicians and economists, notably Paul Krugman of Princeton and the
New York Times op-ed page, have argued that the persistent sluggishness
of the economy is the result of not doing enough. Again, the public
disagrees. As Jodie Allen of Pew wrote about her organization’s study: “Far from
demanding that the government reinforce its efforts so as to help neglected
middle and lower-income groups, a majority of the public views cutting the
federal budget deficit as more important than stimulating the economy.” In June
2009, Pew found that, by 48 percent to 46 percent, Americans favored “spending
more to help [the] recovery” over “reducing the budget deficit.” But in July
2010, deficit-cutting was favored over spending by an 11-point margin, 51-40.
_____________
Government played two distinct roles during and after the crisis. The first
was shoring up shaky financial institutions. On March 24, 2008, the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York issued JPMorgan Chase a $29 billion non-recourse loan
that allowed it to buy Bear Stearns, an investment bank on the verge of
collapse. Six months later, the Fed provided $85 billion (more came later) to
save AIG, the insurance giant with assets of more than $1 trillion. Congress
then enacted the comprehensive Troubled Asset Relief Program, or TARP, which
authorized loans and equity purchases for hundreds of institutions (mainly banks
but also auto companies).
By June 30, 2010, the U.S. Treasury had disbursed $386 billion in TARP
funds. Another $145 billion went to keep afloat the two government-sponsored
(though ostensibly private) institutions that provide lenders with mortgage
money, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac.
How did all that work out? The Bear Stearns, AIG, Fannie Mae, and TARP
dispositions were far from perfect. Robert Pozen argues in his book Too Big
to Save? that too much of the federal money injected into AIG was used to
bail out banks—many of them foreign—that AIG had insured against mortgage losses
through credit default swaps. Those banks, he writes, could have taken a -severe
haircut without jeopardizing the global financial system. Also questionable was
giving General Motors and Chrysler more than $80 billion (though President Bush
acted honorably in keeping the automakers alive until the start of the Obama
administration.) A good case can be made that automakers should have been
allowed to go bankrupt through the normal legal process, with their assets
passing from weak hands to strong. As for Fannie and Freddie, had perfectly
sensible warnings from experts like Peter Wallison been heeded, they might not
have collapsed at all, and the entire subprime-mortgage meltdown might not have
occurred. So far, Congress and the president have simply kicked the
Fannie-Freddie can down the road, delaying a long-term solution.
Overall, however, it has to be said that the TARP and the other financial
rescues were necessary and -efficient. The global financial network did face
systemic failure, mainly because of a lack of liquidity, or cash to meet
immediate demands. The U.S. government was able to provide that liquidity, using
its authority as lender of last resort, and most of the direct beneficiaries
could eventually repay their loans, with interest, as they recovered. In fact,
within a year and a half after the TARP was launched, the Treasury had been
repaid $211 billion—or more than half what it had put out.
The second role government played, however, was far more questionable.
Instead of lender of last resort, it determined to be the spender of
last resort. And this decision, more than any other, is what has led to the
crisis in the liberal economic experiment.
_____________
John Maynard Keynes argued in 1933 that in a deep recession, consumers
and businesses were too frightened and broke to spend and invest, so it was up
to government to do the job with massive public-works projects and short-term
tax cuts. Following Keynes’s theory, Congress and the White House enacted the
American Reinvestment and Recovery Act of 2009, which allotted $787 billion to a
potpourri of stimulus programs to invigorate the economy.
In an article in Commentary (“Stimulus: A History of Folly”) in March 2009, I
recounted the discouraging history of Keynesian stimulus and predicted its
failure this time out as well. The surprise, both to me and I’m sure to those
who planned, advocated, voted for, and implemented the stimulus package, is just
how quickly the American public came to recognize the sweeping nature of the
failure.
The reasons for the failure, and for the literally depressing pessimism that
the failure seems to herald, were first described 160 years ago by Frederic
Bastiat in his essay “The Seen and the Unseen.” Bastiat was describing the
effects of economic actions, including public spending. That spending leads to
results that are “seen,” meaning, in the case of the current stimulus, the jobs
of medical residents, teachers, road builders, and the like—jobs created or
preserved by stimulus dollars. Then there is the matter of what is
“unseen”—meaning all the money government used for those projects that has been
diverted, through -taxes or borrowing, from other uses.
Usually, the public is too dazzled by the seen to take account of the unseen.
So politicians often get away with saying they have “created” this or that many
jobs by spending taxpayers’ money. Few follow the trail back to where the
money came from or project it forward to divine the consequences. That was not
the case this time. Quite the opposite, in fact.
In the current crisis, advocates of stimulus and of government intervention
in general have been badly hurt by two developments. First, the short-term
effects of the stimulus—the “seen”—have been extremely disappointing. The
stimulus was signed into law on February 17, 2009. In the preceding month,
unemployment stood at 7.7 percent. A study released at the time by Christina
Romer, who shortly thereafter became chair of the President’s Council of
Economic Advisers, and Jared Bernstein, economic adviser to Vice President
Biden, predicted that unemployment would never exceed 8 percent and would fall
to 7.5 percent by June 30, 2010, if the stimulus were enacted. Without the
stimulus, they claimed, unemployment would rise to 9 percent.
Instead, unemployment rose above 10 percent and was a still horrific 9.5
percent in June 2010. Perhaps a lack of stimulus spending would have made
matters even worse. No one knows. You can’t do a controlled experiment. But you
can understand the public reaction: We spent all this money, and got almost
nothing.
Bastiat would have appreciated one of the obvious explanations for the
impotence of the stimulus. In 1957, Milton Friedman argued that attempts to
increase consumer demand through government spending are doomed. The reason,
Friedman wrote, is that individuals make their decisions about consumption by
looking at their likely income and wealth far into the future. (He called it the
“permanent income hypothesis.”) If the government starts spending huge sums
today, consumers foresee higher taxes and, by inference, presume that their
lifetime incomes will drop because of the increased level of their tax burden.
If government spending is short-term or one-time-only, which is what the
stimulus was supposed to be, then individuals might be expected to take a more
benign view. But the 2009 stimulus did not take place in a vacuum. It was soon
accompanied by other economic policies and proposals of the Obama administration
and the Democratic Congress: health-care reform extending public coverage to 30
million new people, cap-and-trade energy proposals featuring vastly higher
taxes, and the imminent expiration of the Bush tax cuts at the end of 2010.
Because of these policies, the “unseen” became “seen” in a fashion
devastating to the politicians supporting them. Americans judged that the party
in power intends the radical expansion of the size of government in perpetuity.
That expansion will have to be paid for. There is no reason to expect very much
good from the future if you are the sort of person who generates income and
creates jobs. Your “permanent income” is going to decline, and your gut response
will be to husband your resources.
More disastrously for the Democrats, the “unseen” became “seen” almost
immediately, in the form of metastasizing budget deficits. In order to spend all
that money it didn’t have, the federal government was, of course, forced
to borrow. So Treasury debt held by the public has grown from an easily
manageable 36 percent of GDP at the end of fiscal 2007 to a troubling 62 percent
at the end of 2010. Only once in U.S. history—during and right after World War
II—has the debt-to-GDP ratio ever exceeded 50 percent.
With the new health-care law and other increased spending on the horizon, the
debt-to-GDP ratio will keep rising—to 66 percent in 2020 and 79 percent in 2035,
under what the Congressional Budget Office calls its “extended-baseline”
scenario. In a worst-case scenario (using reasonable assumptions of spending
growth), the ratio may jump to about 100 percent in 2020 and nearly 200 percent
in 2035, predicted the CBO.
Americans are worried about this rising debt, and they have reason to be. As
the CBO puts it, “Unless policymakers restrain the growth of spending, increase
revenues significantly as a share of GDP, or adopt some combination of those two
approaches, growing budget deficits will cause debt to rise to unsupportable
levels.”
What does “unsupportable” mean? Interest rates—and thus borrowing costs—could
rise significantly as lenders worry about America’s ability to repay. And if
history is a guide, a debt-to-GDP ratio in the 100 percent range will seriously
constrain the economy, -according to This Time It’s Different: Eight
Centuries of Financial Folly, a 2009 book by Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth
Rogoff that may turn out to be the most influential analysis of the current
crisis. For the public, the worry extends beyond the debt itself to the very
role of the federal government. According to Gallup, by a margin of 57 percent
to 37 percent, Americans say there is “too much” rather than “not enough
regulation of business by government.” Big business is unloved, but more and
more, government is seen as clumsy, venal, and self-serving.
_____________
There is no denying that the narrative about how greedy financiers caused the
economic crisis still has currency. But another narrative now looms larger. It
is that the government’s attempts to fix the problem through spending have been
ineffectual at best and, more likely, dangerous to our economic health.
When the financial meltdown occurred, it seemed almost certain that Americans
would judge that the conservative economic experiment of 1981-2008 had failed.
Instead, they seem to be leaning in the opposite direction—toward a conclusion
that it was the liberal economic experiment of 2009-10 that has failed.
This conclusion is not being warmly embraced so much as reluctantly conceded.
Things could change. Conservatives will face a challenge later this year over
whether to extend tax cuts that, at least from a “seen” viewpoint, will further
increase the debt. Still, when you consider that a repudiation of free-market
capitalism and what President Sarkozy called a “return of the state” appeared
almost certain when the crisis broke, we should be both humbled by and thankful
for this strange and constructive turn of events.
Home | Articles | BLOG | Quotes | Photo Gallery | Favorites | Stupid Frogs Game | Store | Feedback | Search | Subscribe | About Us
|