Why Obamanomics Has Failed
By ALLAN H. MELTZER
WSJ.com
The administration's stimulus program has failed. Growth is slow and
unemployment remains high. The president, his friends and advisers talk
endlessly about the circumstances they inherited as a way of avoiding
responsibility for the 18 months for which they are responsible.
But they want new stimulus measures—which is convincing evidence that
they too recognize that the earlier measures failed. And so the U.S. was
odd-man out at the G-20 meeting over the weekend, continuing to call for
more government spending in the face of European resistance.
The contrast with President Reagan's antirecession and pro-growth
measures in 1981 is striking. Reagan reduced marginal and corporate tax
rates and slowed the growth of nondefense spending. Recovery began about a
year later. After 18 months, the economy grew more than 9% and it continued
to expand above trend rates.
Two overarching reasons explain the failure of Obamanomics. First,
administration economists and their outside supporters neglected the
longer-term costs and consequences of their actions. Second, the
administration and Congress have through their deeds and words heightened
uncertainty about the economic future. High uncertainty is the enemy of
investment and growth.
Most of the earlier spending was a very short-term response to long-term
problems. One piece financed temporary tax cuts. This was a mistake, and
ignores the role of expectations in the economy. Economic theory predicts
that temporary tax cuts have little effect on spending. Unless tax cuts are
expected to last, consumers save the proceeds and pay down debt. Experience
with past temporary tax reductions, as in the Carter and first Bush
presidencies, confirms this outcome.
Another large part of the stimulus went to relieve state and local
governments of their budget deficits. Transferring a deficit from the state
to the federal government changes very little. Some teachers and police got
an additional year of employment, but their gain is temporary. Any benefits
to them must be balanced against the negative effect of the increased public
debt and the temporary nature of the transfer.
The Obama economic team ignored past history. The two most successful
fiscal stimulus programs since World War II—under Kennedy-Johnson and
Reagan—took the form of permanent reductions in corporate and marginal tax
rates. Economist Arthur Okun, who had a major role in developing the
Kennedy-Johnson program, later analyzed the effect of individual items. He
concluded that corporate tax reduction was most effective.
Another defect of Obamanomics was that part of the increased spending
authorized by the 2009 stimulus bill was held back. Remember the
oft-repeated claim that the spending would go for "shovel ready" projects?
That didn't happen, though spending will flow more rapidly now in an effort
to lower unemployment and claim economic success during the fall election
campaign.
In his January 2010 State of the Union address, President Obama
recognized that the United States must increase exports. He was right, but
he has done little to help, either by encouraging investment to increase
productivity, or by supporting trade agreements, despite his promise to the
Koreans that he repeated in Toronto. Export earnings are the only way to
service our massive foreign borrowing. This should be a high priority. Isn't
anyone in the government thinking about the future?
Mr. Obama has denied the cost burden on business from his health-care
program, but business is aware that it is likely to be large. How large?
That's part of the uncertainty that employers face if they hire additional
labor.
The president asks for cap and trade. That's more cost and more
uncertainty. Who will be forced to pay? What will it do to costs here
compared to foreign producers? We should not expect businesses to invest in
new, export-led growth when uncertainty about future costs is so large.
Then there is Medicaid, the medical program for those with lower incomes.
In the past, states paid about half of the cost, and they are responsible
for 20% of the additional cost imposed by the program's expansion. But
almost all the states must balance their budgets, and the new Medicaid
spending mandated by ObamaCare comes at a time when states face large
deficits and even larger unfunded liabilities for pensions. All this only
adds to uncertainty about taxes and spending.
Other aspects of the Obama economic program are equally problematic. The
auto bailouts ran roughshod over the rule of law. Chrysler bondholders were
given short shrift in order to benefit the auto workers union. By weakening
the rule of law, the president opened the way to great mischief and
increased investors' and producers' uncertainty. That's not the way to get
more investment and employment.
Almost daily, Mr. Obama uses his rhetorical skill to castigate
businessmen who have the audacity to hope for profitable opportunities. No
president since Franklin Roosevelt has taken that route. President Roosevelt
slowed recovery in 1938-40 until the war by creating uncertainty about his
objectives. It was harmful then, and it's harmful now.
In 1980, I had the privilege of advising Prime Minister Margaret Thatcher
to ignore the demands of 360 British economists who made the outrageous
claim that Britain would never (yes, never) recover from her decision to
reduce government spending during a severe recession. They wanted more
spending. She responded with a speech promising to stay with her tight
budget. She kept a sustained focus on long-term problems. Expectations about
the economy's future improved, and the recovery soon began.
That's what the U.S. needs now. Not major cuts in current spending, but a
credible plan showing that authorities will not wait for a fiscal crisis but
begin to act prudently and continue until deficits disappear, and the debt
is below 60% of GDP. Rep. Paul Ryan (R., Wisc.) offered a plan, but the
administration and Congress ignored it.
The country does not need more of the same. Successful leaders give the
public reason to believe that they have a long-term program to bring a
better tomorrow. Let's plan our way out of our explosive deficits and our
hesitant and jobless recovery by reducing uncertainty and encouraging
growth.
Mr. Meltzer is a professor of economics at Carnegie Mellon
University, a visiting scholar at the American Enterprise Institute, and the
author of "A History of the Federal Reserve" (University of Chicago Press,
2003 and 2010).